《Strip Clubs, “Secondary Effects” and Residential Property Prices》

打印
作者
Taggert J. Brooks;Brad R. Humphreys;Adam Nowak
来源
REAL ESTATE ECONOMICS,Vol.48,Issue3,P.850-885
语言
英文
关键字
作者单位
E-mail address: brooks.tagg@uwlax.edu http://orcid.org/0000-0002-6711-3013 Department of Economics, University of Wisconsin‐La Crosse, 1725 State Street, La Crosse, WI, 54601 E-mail address: brooks.tagg@uwlax.edu, E-mail address: brhumphreys@mail.wvu.edu, E-mail address: adam.d.nowak@gmail.com;E-mail address: brhumphreys@mail.wvu.edu College of Business & Economics, West Virginia University, 1601 University Ave. PO Box 6025, Morgantown, WV, 26506‐6025 E-mail address: brooks.tagg@uwlax.edu, E-mail address: brhumphreys@mail.wvu.edu, E-mail address: adam.d.nowak@gmail.com;E-mail address: adam.d.nowak@gmail.com College of Business & Economics, West Virginia University, 1601 University Ave. PO Box 6025, Morgantown, WV, 26506‐6025 E-mail address: brooks.tagg@uwlax.edu, E-mail address: brhumphreys@mail.wvu.edu, E-mail address: adam.d.nowak@gmail.com
摘要
Municipalities regulate sexually oriented businesses (SOBs) through the “secondary effects” doctrine, which justifies limiting First Amendment speech protections inside SOBs. Negative effects of SOBs on nearby neighborhood quality are a frequently cited secondary effect. Little empirical evidence exists that SOBs generate such negative externalities. If SOBs generate negative externalities, then nearby property prices should decrease when a strip club opens. We estimate regression models of housing prices to determine the effect of new clubs on nearby residential property prices in Seattle, exploiting the termination of a 17‐year moratorium on openings and find no evidence that strip clubs have “secondary effects.”